《未來資源研究所:2022水泥和鋼鐵行業創新的需求拉動工具研究報告(英文版)(74頁).pdf》由會員分享,可在線閱讀,更多相關《未來資源研究所:2022水泥和鋼鐵行業創新的需求拉動工具研究報告(英文版)(74頁).pdf(74頁珍藏版)》請在三個皮匠報告上搜索。
1、Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsADemand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsAaron Bergman,Alan Krupnick,Daniel Haerle,Lucie Bioret,Yuqi Zhu,and Jhih-Shyang ShihReport 23-01 March 2023Resources for the FutureiAbout the Authors Aar
2、on Bergman is a fellow at Resources for the Future.Prior to joining RFF,he was the Lead for Macroeconomics and Emissions at the Energy Information Administration(EIA),managing EIAs modeling in those areas.Before working at EIA,Bergman spent over a decade in the policy office at the Department of Ene
3、rgy,working on a broad array of climate and environmental policies.Bergman has worked in the White House at the Office of Science and Technology Policy,managing the Quadrennial Energy Review and handling the methane measurement portfolio,and at the Council on Environmental Quality,working on carbon
4、regulation.Bergman entered the federal government in 2009 as a Science and Technology Policy Fellow with the American Association for the Advancement of Science,after working in high energy physics.Alan Krupnick is a senior fellow at Resources for the Future and an expert on the oil and gas sector,r
5、educing greenhouse gas emissions from this and the industrial sectors,and cost-benefit analysis.In particular,Krupnicks recent research focuses on green public procurement,decarbonized hydrogen and tax credits,and developing markets for green natural gas.His portfolio also includes guiding the value
6、 of information agenda covered by our VALUABLES initiative with NASA,the valuation of reducing asthma risks,estimating the value of statistical life,and issues of regulatory reform.Daniel Haerle is a PhD candidate at the Department of Spatial Economics at VU Amsterdam.His research revolves around cl
7、imate policy and the determinants of green innovation and technology adoption.Lucie BIoret is a research analyst working on industrial decarbonization.Lucie is especially interested in innovation policy for developing low-carbon solutions and in the impact of government support on emissions reductio
8、n efforts.Born and raised in Brittany,France,Lucie recently graduated from AgroParisTech and Universit Paris-Saclay with a masters Degree in Environmental Economics.Yuqi Zhu joined RFF as a senior research associate in 2022 after receiving his masters degree in public policy from the Harvard Kennedy
9、 School.Prior to graduate school,he worked in corporate development at Liberty Media,a media and communications holding company in Denver.Jhih-Shyang Shih is a fellow at RFF.His research interests lie in integrated system analysis of environmental and resource policy and decisionmaking.Shih has exte
10、nsive experience with modeling to study energy and environmental issues(air quality,risk,surface water and solid waste management,and has studied the costs of environmental protection,technology adoption,and renewable energy).Shihs recent research has focused on electric and thermal energy storage;s
11、ustainable infrastructure;integration of renewable and energy storage;bioenergy;water resources and water quality management;energy-water nexus;and integrated assessment of climate change,land use,air and water quality.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsiiAcknow
12、ledgements We would like to thank the Schmidt Futures Foundation and our project officer,Tom Kalil,for financial and intellectual support of this project.We would also like to thank numerous staff at industry trade associations and specific companies who provided us with invaluable information and p
13、erspectives on the topics of this project.Additionally,we would like to thank several experts we talked to at DOE on demand-pull innovation tools,as well as our summer intern Garima Desai,currently a Rhodes Scholar at Oxford University.About RFFResources for the Future(RFF)is an independent,nonprofi
14、t research institution in Washington,DC.Its mission is to improve environmental,energy,and natural resource decisions through impartial economic research and policy engagement.RFF is committed to being the most widely trusted source of research insights and policy solutions leading to a healthy envi
15、ronment and a thriving economy.The views expressed here are those of the individual authors and may differ from those of other RFF experts,its officers,or its directors.Sharing Our WorkOur work is available for sharing and adaptation under an Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International
16、(CC BY-NC-ND 4.0)license.You can copy and redistribute our material in any medium or format;you must give appropriate credit,provide a link to the license,and indicate if changes were made,and you may not apply additional restrictions.You may do so in any reasonable manner,but not in any way that su
17、ggests the licensor endorses you or your use.You may not use the material for commercial purposes.If you remix,transform,or build upon the material,you may not distribute the modified material.For more information,visit https:/creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.Resources for the FutureiiiExe
18、cutive SummaryDemand-pull measures are a set of relatively underused policies for driving innovation by increasing the demand for innovative technologies.These measures contrast with supply-push policies,such as research and development funding,that subsidize the supply of innovative technologies.De
19、mand-pull policies include:Prizes for innovation Advance market commitments(AMCs),which commit to purchase innovative products when developed Government procurement,where the government provides additional demand for innovative technologies Milestone payments,where funding is released in stages at t
20、he completion of various development stages Standards,which can stimulate demand by providing information about technology performance Contracts for differences,which can reduce price volatility-related risk related that can hamper innovationLiterature ReviewWe performed an extensive literature revi
21、ew for each of these policies,particularly looking at their applicability to various stages of innovation.The results of this review are summarized in Table 1.Here,technology readiness level(TRL)gauges the maturity of a particular technology,with lower numbers(13)being early-stage research and devel
22、opment,middle numbers(46)being pilot stage,and the largest numbers(79)being demonstration and commercial deployment.Another important aspect not reflected in the table is that the size of the monetary reward must be comparable to the scale of the goal.This is particularly important for demonstration
23、 projects in the energy sector,which can cost over a billion dollars.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsivTable 1.Summary of Results of Literature ReviewPolicyPolicy typeInducement mechanismTechnology readiness levelDistinct innovation ruleInducement prizesDeman
24、d-pull with push elements Sets up competition to meet well-specified objectives by offering reward 3-6 Funding early-stage R&D with well-defined targets and many competitors Public procurementDemand-pull Government demand for products with low-embodied carbon which can then shape the market8-9Create
25、s market-driven incentives for commercial-ready innovationsAdvance market commitmentsDemand-pull Demand guarantee at a given price and performance level 7-9 Can be forward lookingCan be implemented by private actorsContracts with chosen producers,ex post rewardReduces purchaser riskMIlestone payment
26、sSupply-push with pull elementsFunding where increments are conditional on reaching pre-defined goals2-9Complementary policy with other innovation toolsDe-risks(particularly large)projectsTechnology standardsDemand-pullStandardization of performance of new technologiesReduces transaction costs6-9Oft
27、en a necessary condition for other tools,such as prizes and public procurementProvides information of performanceCarbon contracts for differenceDemand-pullSetting and stabilization of the carbon price incentivizes low-carbon investments7-9Applicable where carbon markets existDemand-Pull Tools for In
28、novation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsvRecent LegislationWhile there has been a welcome increase in the use of these policies in recent years,there is still room to increase their use,particularly in the context of low-carbon technologies.The passage of the Infrastructure,Investment,and J
29、obs Act(IIJA)and the Inflation Reduction Act(IRA)has led to the creation of the Office of Clean Energy Demonstrations at the Department of Energy(DOE),which released a request for information on the use of demand-pull policies in February 2023.These bills appropriated billions of dollars for demonst
30、ration funding by DOE.However,they also included a number of demand-pull policies.These include:Prizes for direct air capture Government procurement of clean building materials as part of the Buy Clean Initiative Carbon intensity standards for concrete Procurement of carbon from direct air capture(i
31、n the Omnibus Appropriations Act)In addition,milestone payments are incorporated in many of the demonstration funding programs by DOE under the IIJA.For example,the hydrogen hubs program releases the funding in four stages,with goals to be met at each stage of the project.Application to Steel and Ce
32、ment We next explore the opportunities for applying demand-pull policies to the iron and steel sector and the cement sector.In each sector,we consider the technologies needed for its decarbonization,the current policy roadmap,and the applicability of demand-pull policies as complements(or substitute
33、s)for current policies.We also separately look at crosscutting technologies such as carbon capture and low-carbon process heat that can help decarbonize these sectors.Steel ProductionThe main technologies to decarbonize steel production use hydrogen and electrolysis.Hydrogen steelmaking is already b
34、eing demonstrated in the HYBRIT project,a Swedish joint venture producing fossil fuel-free steel with hydrogen direct reduction of iron to replace the traditional coal-based technology,and the electrolysis technologies are in the pilot stage.Given that these technologies with high TRL exist and have
35、 the potential to almost completely decarbonize the sector,funding for demonstration projects is likely the most important funding mechanism.There may be opportunities to enable use of lower-quality steel in electric arc furnaces.AMCs and government procurement are demand-pull tools that could also
36、help deployment,but given the multi-billion dollar cost of a single steel plant,large sums of money would have to be devoted to such mechanisms.With respect to prizes,they work best with multiple competitors,and the steel industry is highly concentrated in the United States.Demand-Pull Tools for Inn
37、ovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsviThere may be opportunities for AMCs along the value chain,such as in intermediate,fabricated steel products(such as sheets,plates,bars,beams,pipes,and tubes)due to the large number of promising technologies and a considerably higher degree of diversi
38、ty in final products that use steel.Government procurement,while likely not sufficient to drive deployment of zero-carbon steelmaking by itself,can still provide a valuable source of revenue for producers.Carbon intensity standards are being developed to enable procurement under the Buy Clean Initia
39、tive.CementUnlike iron and steel,where the technologies are at higher TRLs,low-to zero-carbon cement is still in the research and development stage.We find that the development of a low-to zero-carbon cement has many of the characteristics that make the use of prizes beneficial,such as low TRLs,prod
40、uct uniformity,and existing emissions reporting systems.Specifying a prize for cement will require a detailed set of material standards to ensure the material can be widely used as a substitute for current cement uses.There would also need to be a specification for the amount of carbon involved in t
41、he creation of this cement.Given the need to achieve net-zero carbon emissions by the second half of the century,we suggest that the standard for carbon emissions be a very high percentage reduction from current carbon intensities.Another choice is whether to focus on all embodied emissions in the c
42、oncrete sector or to focus on the process emissions.We suggest that the standard focus on the process emissions,since those are the emissions fundamental to cement creation and that cannot be abated in any other manner.As there are proposed alternate cements that absorb carbon dioxide as they cure,r
43、emoving carbon from the atmosphere,these negative emissions should be included in any carbon accounting.Finally,any such cement substitute must be deployable at scale.In particular,this means that any feedstocks into the production process must be relatively inexpensive and available in large quanti
44、ties.Similarly,the price differential as compared to traditional cement,perhaps expressed in terms of an implicit carbon price,must be reasonable.Because AMCs can be made for future products,they may be more applicable to demonstrate low-carbon cement technologies as they progress beyond pilot scale
45、.While individual cement plants can be quite expensive,the overall scale of cement use in the United States means that there is likely enough capital to enable sufficiently large AMCs to be effective.The development of requirements for such a prize or AMC is a substantial endeavor in itself.For inst
46、ance,the value of the prize or the price of the AMC must be determined,balancing the cost to the government with the need to incentivize the research and benefits of success.We believe that the benefits of a low-carbon,scalable cement are substantial,which would justify a relatively large prize or m
47、arket commitment.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsviiCarbon Capture and Process HeatCarbon capture,utilization,and storage(CCUS)and zero-carbon process heat are technologies that can be deployed across a wide array of sectors and are also applicable to steelma
48、king and cement manufacture.However,because neither of these technologies are products that anyone purchases,it is not immediately clear whether a demand-pull policy is desirable.One could use prizes or AMCs for products produced using CCUS or zero-carbon process heat,but it would likely be more eff
49、icient to instead set a standard for the carbon content of the final product and then be agnostic with respect to how the manufacturing process achieves that standard.One exception to this may be milestone payments,which,because they can apply at lower TRLs,could be used for funding more nascent car
50、bon capture and process heat technologies.Nonetheless,there are two specific technologies,both applicable to cement,that might benefit from demand-pull policies.The first is the use of chemical looping,a form of carbon capture that involves limestone,a major ingredient in cement manufacture.Given th
51、is synergy,policies that target this technology could have substantial benefits for decarbonizing cement.Cement also requires very high temperature process heat that has traditionally not been able to be supplied by electricity.Demand-pull policies for process heat that are applicable to cement coul
52、d lead to the elimination of the combustion emissions from its manufacture,leaving only a pure process emissions stream that is much easier to capture.We have not identified particular carbon capture or process heat technologies in iron and steel that are good candidates for demand-pull policies.Con
53、clusionsDOE faces huge challenges to meet its new decarbonization goals.In a tight labor market,it needs to hire people knowledgeable about CO2 mitigation and efficient decision-making.Even with all the cash flowing and subsidies,its grantees may be reluctant to propose and promise success for massi
54、ve projects with unproven(at scale)technologies and with private funding hard to come by.By focusing on boosting demand,demand-pull policies can reduce offtake risks,making private capital financing a better bet.However,these tools will not implement themselves.Green procurement,for instance,require
55、s carbon intensity benchmarks,environmental product declarations,and decision-making tools that need knowledgeable staff and time and resources to learn how to design and use them.Early failures,in the face of all the pressure to succeed quickly,need to be expected and tolerated.Legal and administra
56、tive barriers may also limit the application of some tools we reviewed,although the relevant agencies have used some types of these tools before.Ultimately,greater reliance on these tools requires high-level administrative commitment and,perhaps,a willingness to be patient.As with more traditional s
57、upply-push policies,demand-pull policies inherently involve picking winners and will be less efficient than policies that cut across sectors and provide medium-and long-term incentives to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.Such policies as carbon taxes,tradable performance standards and other regulator
58、y approaches have recently been off the table legislatively.But they need their day in the sun,as well.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel SectorsviiiContentsExecutive Summary iiiLiterature Review iiiRecent Legislation vApplication to Steel and Cement vSteel Production
59、vCement viCarbon Capture and Process Heat viiConclusions vii1.Introduction 12.Stage Setting 22.1.Different Stages of Innovation 22.2.Innovation at the Department of Energy 42.3.Decarbonization Innovation outside of Government 83.Policy Options for Incentivizing Innovation 93.1.Motivation for Innovat
60、ion Policy 93.2.Types of Innovation Tools 103.2.1.Supply-Push Policies 163.2.2.Demand-pull policies 183.2.3.Regulations and Tax Credits 253.2.4.Summary of Tools 264.Developments in Government Funding for Innovation 264.1.Relevant Legislation 264.1.1.Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act 264.1.2.Inf
61、lation Reduction Act 284.1.3.CHIPS and Science Act 284.2.Green Procurement Initiatives 294.3.Prizes 304.4.The ARPA Model 32Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectorsix5.Applications to Iron and Steel and Cement Sectors,and Crosscutting Technologies 335.1.Opportunities
62、for Application to Iron and Steel 335.1.1.Industry Overview 335.1.2.Technology Background 345.1.3.Funding Roadmap 375.1.4.Applicability of Demand-Pull Mechanisms 385.2.Opportunities for Application to Cement 405.2.1.Industry Overview 405.2.2.Technology Background 415.2.3.Funding Roadmap 435.2.4.Appl
63、icability of Demand-Pull Mechanisms 445.3.Crosscutting Technologies 465.3.1.Carbon Capture 475.3.2.Process Heat 515.3.3.Demand-Pull Policies 526.Conclusions 527.References 55Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors11.IntroductionMeeting the US net-zero greenhouse gas
64、(GHG)emissions goal by 2050 will require massive reductions in emissions from all emitting sectors.While the power and transportation sectors are responsible for a large share of GHG emissions,the industrial sector comes in third,with annual emissions of 1,521 million metric tons(Mt)in 2019,one-quar
65、ter of US GHG emissions(EPA 2022).The industrial sector is expected to become the largest set of sources by the next decade,with the top emitters being steel,concrete,chemicals,and refineries.These industries are hard to decarbonize because their capital stock is expensive and turns over slowly,they
66、 often need very high heat sources,and many have process emissions,meaning that the emissions are an inherent part of the chemistry and cannot be abated by fuel substitution.To bring about carbon reductions in this sector,government policies will need to require or otherwise incentivize making such
67、reductions.These policies(defined loosely)include planning documents,such as the US Department of Energys Industrial Decarbonization Roadmap(DOE 2022d),as well as state and private decarbonization roadmaps;regulatory and tax subsidy policies(the sticks and carrots);and a variety of policies that dir
68、ectly stimulate innovation as either supply push offering money to innovators in the form of grants or low-interest and guaranteed loansor what we refer to as demand pull policies,a relatively underutilized class of innovation policies such as prizes,advance market commitments,green procurement,and
69、contracts for differences.1This paper is about whether such demand-pull policies offer advantages over(or can complement)supply-push policies for stimulating innovation in the cement and steel industries in the context of DOE innovation policies,as well as those of the US Environmental Protection Ag
70、ency(EPA)and US General Services Administration(GSA)for green procurement.We focus primarily on DOE,however,because of its long history in supporting research,development,and demonstration(RD&D)and because it is the focus of almost all new government spending for industrial decarbonization.We start
71、in Section 2 by discussing the innovation process and the technology readiness scale that figures heavily in DOEs work and in this paper.In Section 3,we describe the full set of tools affecting innovation,including supply-push and demand-pull innovation policies,as well as regulation,tax subsidies,p
72、rivate R&D programs,and several other categories,pointing out the pros and cons of each.This section is partly based on a detailed review of the academic literature and includes comments on practical experience with these policies.In Section 4,we examine recent trends in government RD&D,including in
73、 demand-pull policies.In Section 5,we explore the opportunities for applying demand-pull policies to the iron and steel sector and the cement sector.For each sector,we consider the technologies needed for decarbonization,the current policy roadmap,and the applicability of demand-pull policies as com
74、plements(or substitutes)for current policies.We also separately look at crosscutting technologies,such as carbon capture and low-carbon process heat,that can help decarbonize these sectors.Section 6 concludes with suggestions for the role of demand-pull policies going forward.1 Some policies may not
75、 directly be innovation policies but may work through building de-mand to obtain innovation.We classify those by their main characteristic.Resources for the Future22.Stage Setting2.1.Different Stages of InnovationThere are many ways to classify the innovation process,but for the purposes of this pap
76、er,we use DOEs Technology Readiness Level(TRL)scale(DOE 2011).This scale,shown in Table 2,was originally developed for use by NASA and adopted by DOE for use in Technology Readiness Assessments.The TRL scale indicates the maturity level of a given technology and ranges from 1(basic principles)to 9(t
77、otal system used successfully in project operations).Other TRL scales exist,of which the most prominent was developed by the International Energy Agency,whose scale has 11 points and refers to both technological development and market adoption(IEA 2020b).Table 2.DOEs Technology Readiness Level Scale
78、Relative level of technology developmentTechnology readiness levelTRL definitionBasic Technology ResearchTRL 1Basic principles observed and reportedTRL 2Technology concept and/or application formulatedResearch to Prove FeasibilityTRL 3Analytical and experimental critical function and/or characterist
79、ic proof of conceptTechnology DevelopmentTRL 4Component and/or process validation in relevant environmentTRL 5Laboratory scale,similar system validation in relevant environmentTechnology DemonstrationTRL 6Engineering/pilot-scale,similar(protoypical)system validation in a relevant environmentSystem C
80、ommissioningTRL 7Full-scale,similar(prototypical)system demonstrated in a relevant environmentTRL 8Actual system completed and qualified through test and demonstrationSystem OperationsTRL 9Actual system operated over the full range of expected conditionsSource:DOE(2011,22,Table 4).Demand-Pull Tools
81、for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors3At the lowest levels of the DOE scale is the Basic Technology Research(TRLs 12)phase.In this phase,scientific research is translated into a technologys basic principles and speculative practical applications,and the goal is to begin determining
82、 potential use cases through analytical studies.Next is the Research to Prove Feasibility(TRLs 23)phase,which includes additional applied research along with laboratory-scale studies.This phase is composed of analytical studies along with laboratory-scale studies that can help validate hypothesized
83、use cases.The basic components are then integrated into a laboratory-scale system to establish that they work together in the Technology Development(TRLs 45)phase.This system configuration is likely to be similar to the eventual application of the technology.In the Technology Demonstration(TRL 6)pha
84、se,the technology moves beyond the lab,and engineering-scale prototypes are tested in a relevant environment.This is akin to a pilot phase and is a significant step up from the laboratory work in previous phases.From this phase onward,projects likely require partnerships with the private sector to f
85、urther validate the technology.This is followed by full-scale testing in the System Commissioning(TRLs 78)phase,which marks the end of system development for the technology.In this phase,the technology undergoes rigorous testing as a full-scale prototype.The goal is to prove that the technology can
86、function under expected conditions(e.g.,with real feedstock under certain weather conditions).In its final form,the technology reaches the System Operations(TRL 9)phase and can operate under a full range of conditions.Technologies that reach this phase are expected to be fully commercialized and cap
87、able of operating at scale.Overlaid on this scale is a concept called the“innovation valley of death”(Figure 1).This term describes the point in the technology development process at which basic research has proven out and the projects are ready to be developed into pilots and prototypes,but univers
88、ity and government funding typically peters out,while venture capital and other private capital assess the investment risk as too high.This issue is especially relevant in the energy technology area,where capital requirements for demonstrations are high and development timelines are usually longer t
89、han traditional venture capitals timelines.Thus good ideas may not make it out of this valley without purposeful programs to derisk projects,such as through targeted government innovation programs(Nemet et al.2018).Resources for the Future42.2.Innovation at the Department of EnergyCertain offices at
90、 DOE focus efforts on specific categories of the TRL scale(Figure 2).For example,basic science research(TRLs 13)is explicitly supported by the Office of Science,while the Advanced Research Projects AgencyEnergy(ARPA-E)and the Small Business Innovation Research and Small Business Technology Transfer(
91、SBIR/STTR)programs also fund lab-scale prototyping(TRLs 26 and 15,respectively ).On the other end of the scale,the Loan Programs Office(LPO)supports commercial-scale deployment projects that have advanced beyond the development phase(TRLs 89).The Office of Clean Energy Demonstrations(OCED),created i
92、n 2021,bridges the gap in funding between programs focusing on technology developments and LPO funding technology deployments.It helps innovations escape the valley of death by supporting large-scale demonstration projects.Both OCED and LPO are multitechnology offices that have authorization to fund
93、 projects that span the decarbonization landscape.LPO,through loan guarantees and financing in support of or in lieu of private sector financing,focuses primarily on initial commercial deployments,whereas OCED provides support for projects that are beyond the early-stage demonstration phase but are
94、still too risky for full-scale commercial deployment.Each can fulfill a vital role in bridging the valley of death.Figure 1.The Innovation Valley of DeathSource:Skillicorn(2021).Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors5Most of DOEs technology offices involved in adva
95、ncing industrial decarbonization efforts have activities covering the entire TRL scale(Table 3).Historically,industrial decarbonization activity has mainly taken place in the Advanced Manufacturing Office(AMO)in the office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy(EERE),but other offices have also p
96、layed important roles,such as the Office of Fossil Energy and Carbon Management(FECM)for carbon capture technologies.In 2022,AMO reorganized and split its RD&D funding between the newly created Industrial Efficiency and Decarbonization Office(IEDO)and Advanced Materials and Manufacturing Technologie
97、s Office(AMMTO).Priorities within these subprograms can range from earlier-stage R&D in partnership with national labs and universities to later-stage pilot and demonstration projects.Similarly,FECM has an array of programs that fund both new technologies and demonstration of more proven approaches.
98、For example,FECMs Point Source Carbon Capture Program,which prioritizes the cement,steel,and hydrogen production sectors,is focusing on new capture technologies in addition to technologies in its portfolio that are in the demonstration phase.While these offices have primarily relied on traditional R
99、D&D funding through funding opportunity announcements(FOAs)and grants,they also have a limited number of creative funding mechanisms,such as prizes,other forms of competitions,and technical assistance.22 We use the term grants to include other forms of contracting,such as cooperative agreements.Figu
100、re 2.Technology Readiness Level Focus of DOE OfficeSource:Walrond(2022).Resources for the Future6Table 3.DOE Offices for Industrial DecarbonizationDOE OfficeRole in Supporting Industrial DecarbonizationAdvanced Manufacturing Office,Energy Efficiency&Renewable EnergyEEREs Advanced Manufacturing Offic
101、e(AMO)supports development of new manufacturing processes and products and is dedicated to improving the energy efficiency,material efficiency,productivity,and competitiveness of manufacuters across the industrial sector.Bioenergy Technologies Office,Energy Efficiency&Renweable EnergyEEREs Bioenergy
102、 Technoloy Office(BETO)supports development of low-carbon fuels and energy through focus on alternative feedstocks(e.g.,biomass,waste,CO2)and process improvements through manufacturing.Fuel Cell Technologies Office,Energy Efficiency&Renweable EnergyEEREs Hydrogen and Fuel Cell Technologies Office(HF
103、TO)works to advance the development of hydrogen and fuel cell technologies for multiple decarbonization opportunities across industrial sectors and applicationsSolar Energy Technologies Office,Energy Efficiency&Renewable EnergyEEREs Solar Energy Technology Office(SETO)supports development of solar p
104、rocesses.For decarbonization,a main focus includes solar thermal industrial process heat for thermally-driven processes across multiple manufacturing subsectors.Strategic Analysis,Energy Efficiency&Renweable EnergyEEREs Strategic Analysis team(SA)sponsors crosscutting analysis and model development
105、across multiple technology areas relevant to the key strategies for industrial decarbonization.ARPA-EThe Advanced Research Projects Agency Energy(ARPA-E)supports development of low-maturity technologies and processes across the four decarbonization pillars.Recent supported topic areas include zero-e
106、missions iron and steel making,cement production emissions reduction,and industrial process heating decarbonization.Fossil Energy and Carbon ManagementDOEs Office of Fossil Fuel Energy and Carbon Management(FECM)supports all areas of the CCUS value chain/system and is a leader in CCUS life cycle ass
107、essment and techno-economic analysis.Office of Nuclear EnergyDOEs Office of Nuclear Enery(NE)supports development of new applications of nuclear beynd electricity(e.g.,small modular,flexible,advanced reactors)to help decarbonize the economy and develop the potential future energy system.Office of El
108、ectricityDOEs Office of Electricity(OE)R&D focuses on technologies leading to a reliable and resilient electric grid that can safely integrate the technologies pursued by other DOE applied offices.Office of ScienceDOEs Office of Science(SC)supports development of discovery and use-inspired fundament
109、al science(low-maturity technologies and processes)to decarbonize industry and transform advanced manufacturing.SC helps define priority research directions to transform advanced manufacturing and decarbonize industry.Source:DOE 2022d.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel
110、 Sectors7Other offices,such as the Bioenergy Technologies(BETO),Hydrogen and Fuel Cell Technologies(HFTO),and Solar Energy Technologies(SETO)Offices,all within EERE,as well as DOEs Office of Nuclear Energy(NE),allocate some funding specifically to scale,pilot,and demonstrate technologies that are fa
111、rther along the TRL scale.This is typically in addition to several other RD&D initiatives within these offices that are TRL-agnostic.BETO and HFTO both have System Development and Integration subprograms,which work on the development,testing,and verification of engineering-scale R&D projects.HFTO su
112、pports the Hydrogen Shot initiative and seeks to demonstrate hydrogens role in end uses such as energy storage,industrial and chemical manufacturing,and transportation.SETO focuses on strengthening manufacturing and value chain capacity,and its American-Made Solar Prize supports the launch of new pr
113、oducts with a focus on domestic manufacturing.The Advanced Reactor Demonstration Program,run jointly by NE and OCED,does not directly fund demonstration projects,but rather serves as a complement to OCEDs multiyear funding for nuclear reactor demonstration and commercial deployments.This program fun
114、ds later-stage R&D and complementary elements necessary to further derisk these deployments,with four pillars focused on innovation,risk reduction,regulatory development,and safeguards.In general,DOEs technology offices have flexibility as to which stage of the TRL scale their subprograms and initia
115、tives target.Over time,funding requests for some subprograms may increase once new technologies become more proven and a shift toward higher-TRL activities is necessary.LPO focuses on high-TRL technology ready for deployment and diffusion.It provides funds through five programs:the Title 17 Innovati
116、ve Clean Energy Loan Guarantee Program,Advanced Technology Vehicles Manufacturing Loan Program,Tribal Energy Loan Guarantee Program,Carbon Dioxide Transportation Infrastructure Finance and Innovation Program(in partnership with FECM),and Energy Infrastructure Reinvestment Program.OCED focuses on a s
117、lightly lower TRL than LPO,where there is still a high technological risk.Its portfolio includes the following programs:Advanced Reactor Demonstration Projects,Carbon Capture Large-Scale Pilot Projects,Carbon Capture Demonstration Projects,Clean Energy Demonstration on Current and Former Mine Land,E
118、nergy Improvements in Rural or Remote Areas,Industrial Demonstrations,Long-Duration Energy Storage Demonstrations,Regional Clean Hydrogen Hubs,and Regional Direct Air Capture Hubs.Additionally,as discussed in Section 4,recent legislation includes major funding provisions for OCED and the technology
119、offices that could address needs in higher-level TRL activities.Of the$62 billion appropriated to DOE from 2022 to 2026,$41.7 billion could be devoted to RD&D(DOE 2021;Chong and Hart 2022).As a result,changes may occur in the technology offices programs,with more RD&D funding allocated explicitly fo
120、r pilot projects and demonstrations.Resources for the Future82.3.Decarbonization Innovation outside of GovernmentWhile governments make funds available for innovations,whether on the demand or supply side,the private sector usually spends sizable sums on innovation and then,to more fully realize the
121、 fruits of such innovations while operating in a competitive market,uses the patent system to protect its intellectual property.From a decarbonization perspective,however,unless an innovation adds to profitability(by adding to revenue or reducing costs),it is unlikely to be made or implemented by th
122、e private sector.So industry is unlikely to invest in decarbonization innovation without regulation,government funding,or some other inducement to do so.Nevertheless,decarbonization is often a joint product with profitable technologies,such as those delivering energy efficiency,which both decreases
123、energy bills and reduces CO2 as a result of burning less fossil energy.The huge reductions in CO2 emissions from substituting cheaper natural gas for coal in power generation are another example of how greater profitability can lead to major CO2 reductions in the absence of regulation.Firms are know
124、n to be strategic about their RD&D spending,realizing that future regulations may be preempted or weakened if emissions reductions can be delivered“early.”Moreover,as a fairly recent phenomenon,shareholders,boards of directors,rating agencies,and lenders all put pressure to varying degrees on indust
125、ry to be a good corporate citizenfor instance,to set and implement goals for reducing greenhouse gas emissions within the firm.Thus some degree of emissions-reducing activities will occur in the absence of regulation or government-supported innovation funding.But this private action in the absence o
126、f government regulations or incentives is extremely unlikely to produce the level of emissions reductions needed to achieve national climate goals.Besides the industrial and financial sectors,other elements of the broad private sector are active in seeking to decarbonize industry,including the tech
127、and other relatively clean sectors and private foundation spinoffs.One major development in the tech sector has been led by Stripe,Meta,Alphabet,McKinsey Sustainability,and Shopify,which have entered into a partnership to offer advance market commitments(a form of demand-pull mechanism discussed in
128、Section 3.2.2.3)with companies developing permanent carbon removal technologies and facilities.The Frontier Fund,formed to oversee this task,is capitalized at almost$1 billion to obtain CO2 reduction credits that the fund contributors will use to meet their own net-zero CO2 goals while making credit
129、s available to other businesses(Frontier 2022).While the targeted technologies,such as direct air capture,are not strictly industrial decarbonization technologies,their maturation could mean that industry might meet its goals in part through purchase of such credits.The green foundation community ha
130、s also been seeking to decarbonize industry and created a number of venture capital spinoffs for funding the development of decarbonizing technologies.One of the most prominent is Breakthrough Energy Ventures fund.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors93.Policy Opt
131、ions for Incentivizing InnovationIn this section,we consider why tools to stimulate innovation are needed and review the types of tools available.We describe both supply-push and demand-pull policies and provide a summary of the literature on demand-pull technologies.Finally,we briefly discuss regul
132、atory measures(sticks)and tax credits(carrots),which can have an ancillary benefit of inducing innovation.3.1.Motivation for Innovation PolicyGovernment intervention is justified in the presence of uninternalized externalities.Within the area of industrial decarbonization,the obvious uninternalized
133、externality is greenhouse gas emissions,which lead to damaging climate change.Internalizing this externality would have two important effects.One is that it would incentivize polluters to reduce their carbon footprint to the point where their tax payment and marginal abatement costs are equal.In the
134、 short term,these costs may be large,given existing GHG-reducing options.The other,in the longer term,is that avoiding the tax would provide incentives to the market to develop and implement new technologies.In addition,the market for innovations and the process of bringing them to commercialization
135、 have their own market failures.One is a lack of appropriability.The patent system exists to provide innovators the ability to profit from their innovations for an extended period of time without direct competition.But minor changes in technologies can skirt patent protection,and in the longer term,
136、the patent ends,diminishing the ability of innovators to appropriate their ideas.Financial markets also have their own failures,such as the valley of death discussed in Section 2.1,a period in an innovation life cycle between small pilots and commercialization in which finding private finance is dif
137、ficult.Thus both regulatory and innovation policies can be justified by market failures.Recognizing these failures,the tax code permits R&D expenses to be deducted against revenues,after they are capitalized and amortized.This reflects a tightening of tax rules,which had permitted all R&D to be expe
138、nsed.Further,an R&D tax credit can be taken for truly innovative projects(around 6 to 7 percent),and start-ups with little tax liability can take the credit against payroll taxes.Resources for the Future103.2.Types of Innovation ToolsThis section describes a set of policy instruments that can be use
139、d to bring about innovation in the industrial sector.We classify each instrument as either supply push,meaning it targets increasing the supply of innovations,or demand pull,meaning it augments the demand for innovations.This definition differs slightly from that used by Nemet et al.(2018),who class
140、ify supply-push policies as those that reduce the cost of innovation and demand-pull policies as those that increase the returns to innovation.The two types of policies complement one another,although in practice,either one type or the other is often used.Moreover,some types of demand-pull policies
141、are more appropriate for lower-TRL innovation and others for furthering penetration of high-TRL technologies.For each instrument,we performed an in-depth literature review to find theoretical and empirical evidence regarding the conditions in which such policies could succeed.In Table 4,each policy
142、instrument listed in the first column appears in a single row,with its main characteristics and some preliminary conclusions on applicability to the industrial sector.The second column indicates whether each instrument fits into a supply-push or demand-pull logic,and the third describes the mechanis
143、m that incentivizes innovation.The TRLs in the fourth column denote the stage of the innovation process in which the policy would be the most relevant.The fifth column identifies the policys distinct innovation role,or its particular niche.The evidence for the success of a given instrument from the
144、theoretical and empirical point of view appears in the sixth column.The second column from the right describes the potential application of each innovation tool to the industrial sector.Finally,the last column presents potential challenges,barriers to the success of each instrument.Table 4.Policy In
145、struments Characteristics SummaryPolicyPolicy typeInducement mechanismTRLDistinct innovation roleEvidenceApplicability to industrial sectorChallengesTraditional grants and cooperative agreementsSupply pushEx ante funding rewards RD&D projects with different level of funder involvement.19Historical p
146、recedentAgency defaultThese effectively reduce costs of new clean energy technologies chosen for funding.These are suitable for directed industrial RD&D.The traditional size of these instruments is usually insufficient for the demonstration stage of clean technology in carbon-intensive sectors.Howev
147、er,IRA money has changed that.Government,instead of the market,selects technologies and grantees.Public loans and loan guaranteesSupply pushPublic funding substitutes for and augments the traditional commercial loan system.9Commerical deplyoment of higher risk projectsThese loans address the second
148、valley of death.There is an enviable record of loan repayments.Public funding is relevant for deployment of large infrastructure.Long payback might not be suited for a fast-changing market.Such funding can involve burdensom processes and cash-flow requirements.Targeted research funding(ARPA model)Su
149、pply pushEx ante funding rewards high-risk projects and helps in upscaling.16Highest risk-rewardPrograms such as DARPA and ARPA-E brought about successful innovations in the defense and energy sectorsSuch funding is suitable for directed RD&D.Supply-push elements in the policy mix are crucial for ea
150、rly-stage innovation but often lack a link to the market.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors11 Inducement prizesDemand pull with push elementsSets up competition to meet well-specified objectives by offering reward.36Funding early-stage R&D with well-defined tar
151、gets and many competitorsLiterature suggests that prizes are more effective when the goal is well defined,but there is a need for an inventive step.Historical prizes suffered from bias and poor design and generated fewer knowledge spillovers than patents.However,experience with prices in government
152、under the COMPETES Reauthorization Act has been extensive and generally positive.Prizes often prioritize participation over economic efficiency.Many participants report that benefits that are not explicitly part of the prize,such as publicity,are important to participation.A low embodied carbon foot
153、print represents a simple performance target for prizes.Quality requirements are well defined in the materials sector(e.g.,cement).Prizes must be well aligned with intellectual property,which is not trivial.Efficiency is reinforced with a complementary link to the market.Prizes can reduce subsequent
154、 innovation by setting target too soon.Prize design requires extensive consultation.It can be challenging to determine the appropriate value and form of the prize.Specificity and transparency of the goal are extremely important to reduce risk for participants.Prizes can lead to duplication of effort
155、 by participants.Resources for the Future12Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors13Public procurement(PP)Demand pullGovernment demand can shape the market by demanding products with low embodied carbon.89Creating market-driven incentives for commercial-ready innova
156、tionsPP has shaped demand significantly,given the large governmental purchasing power in many sectors.There is some empirical evidence on PP stimulating green innovation.A significant part of the material demand in the economy stems from government projects.Requiring low-emissions content may provid
157、e strong incentives for producers to invest in necessary productions.Green PP such as the Buy Clean California Act or the green performance standards for cement and concrete products are now included in the Buy Clean EO.PP must balance the need for low costs with stimulating innovation.Technologies
158、must be sufficiently mature to be affected by the pull incentive of procurement.PP needs accepted green standards to be effective.PP can deploy the adoption of standards,but there is a risk of crowding out private demand.Advance market commitments(AMCs)Demand pullGuarantee demand at a given price an
159、d performance level.79Potentially forward lookingPotentially implemented by private actorsContracting with chosen producers,ex post rewardReducing purchaser riskEvidence on AMCs is primarily based on experience in the pharmaceutical sector,where they have been implemented with great success.For inst
160、ance,the creation of Gavi,the Vaccine Alliance,allowed long-term sustained financing of vaccination programs by using AMC-like contracts.Industry is more capital-intensive than pharma and benefits less from scale.AMCs in the industrial sector might come at a greater cost.The private sector likes AMC
161、s for meeting net-zero pledgesSetting contract terms is difficult.Incentives may be unrealistic or take too long to meet performance goals.TRL must reach 9.Milestone paymentsSupply push with pull elementsProvide funding where increments are conditional on reaching predefined goals29Complementary pol
162、icy with other innovation toolsDerisk projects,particularly large onesTheoretical work posits that milestone structures in R&D contracts can increase efficiency by addressing moral hazard in innovation effort.The NASA Commercial Orbital Transportation Services program seems to have successfully brou
163、ght about the desired innovation;however,no benefit-cost analysis is available.These payments can be incorporated in most tools funding industrial sectors where large projects dominate.The milestones need to be clearly defined to maximize efficiency.Development of a payment schedule is challenging.T
164、echnology standardsDemand pullStandardize performance of new technologies,which reduce transaction costs.69Often a necessary condition for other tools,such as prizes and public procurementMany studies have been conducted of innovation to meet environmental stanrdards,but costs are higher than with p
165、erformance standards.Successful standard setting has taken place in EPAs Environmentally Preferable Purchasing Program.Low-carbon standards provide benchmarks for hard-to-abate sectors.Standards are more efficient when implemented at a stage of the value chain where products are the most homogenous.
166、Setting standards at appropriate product or process level is challenging and requires much industry input.There is a risk of depressed innovation through the strengthening of intellectual property and technology lock-ins.Resources for the Future14Carbon contracts for difference(CCfDs)Demand pullSet
167、and stabilize the carbon price,incentivizing low-carbon investments79Applicable where carbon markets existFrom a theoretical perspective,CCfDs are addressing regulatory risk and financing issues in innovative investments.There has not been a direct application of this concept to carbon prices so far
168、.However,similar instruments are used in France and the UK to guarantee a certain future electricity price to renewable projects.CCfDs are potentially a very powerful tool,given the large capital requirements and long planning horizons for investments in the industrial sector.There may be significan
169、t potential for CCfD-type provisions in tender processes or other market-based policies such as AMCs.Setting the strike price can be a challenge.Context is needed for an uncertain carbon price to be stabilized.Determining the amount of abatement to a given project can be difficult.Demand-Pull Tools
170、for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors15The innovation-stimulating policies listed in Table 4 all have pros and cons relative to one another and the ideal.In the following subsections,we summarize the findings of our literature review.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement a
171、nd Iron and Steel Sectors163.2.1.Supply-Push PoliciesDOEs primary tools for stimulating innovation are competitive grants,low-interest loans,and loan guarantees,which we classify as supply-push policies because they target innovating companies and other institutions,as opposed to creating demand for
172、 such technologies or the products they help produce.3.2.1.1.Traditional grants and cooperative agreementsMost of DOEs innovation spending is through traditional grants and cooperative agreements.Existing literature finds many positive benefits of these programs.For example,traditional RD&D programs
173、 can effectively reduce capital costs of new clean energy technologies.This is in part due to the increase in technological experience and knowledge stock in the form of technology diffusion(Samadi 2018).As experience with new technologies and processes increases,especially with smaller-scale modula
174、r technologies,costs may decline.Additional work has been done to quantify the value of this funding on the creation of new patents(Myers and Lanahan 2022).However,these necessarily involve the government choosing which projects to fund and can come with strings attached,such as a requirement for en
175、vironmental justice and community benefits plans to be submitted with the application.Many DOE funding opportunities target innovation at the lower end of the TRL scale(TRLs 15).At higher TRLs,energy technologies are often complex,integrated systems with numerous individual components,which require
176、piloting,demonstrations,and integration with existing systems(Hart 2017).Thus traditional grants with smaller dollar values may have limited effectiveness for higher-cost technologies seeking to cross the valley of death.3.2.1.2.Loan guarantees and low-interest loansLoan guarantees are another tool
177、that DOE has for supply-push innovation policy.DOE was first authorized to make loan guarantees in the Energy Policy Act of 2005,but the LPOs first loan was not until 2009.Since then,the office has issued over$35 billion of low-interest loans(benchmarked at the relevant US Treasury rate plus a sprea
178、d)and loan guarantees to more than 30 projects that either sought their first commercialization of decarbonization investment or were farther up the innovation process to full market acceptance.LPO also supplies expertise to its borrowers.LPOs programs address the part of the valley of death at whic
179、h technologies move beyond the prototype phase and toward deployment;some call this the“second valley of death”(Hart 2017).In energy innovation,the costs and risks of demonstration are often higher than in other fields and have longer development times,discouraging private investors(Hart 2017).By fu
180、nding the initial demonstration of these technologies,the LPO serves an important role in derisking these investmentsgiving private investors greater comfort with planned projects.Resources for the Future17As with any of the supply-push approaches,a common criticism of the LPO is that winners are pi
181、cked instead of being selected through a market-based mechanism(Bhandary et al.2021).Specific to LPO,only certain types of innovations fit into its programs,and they must meet a threshold size.Interviews conducted by Bhandary et al.(2021)have noted that project developers were uncertain about their
182、eligibility.Because of the lack of transparency,confusion arose around the selection of recipients that were large firms rather than smaller ones.This has raised the concern that this program seems to favor large corporations over smaller firms.Moreover,some potential applicants“were discouraged by
183、the time-consuming process and high transaction costs involved”(Bhandary et al.2021).In the past,project developers seeking loan guarantees paid a risk-based credit subsidy cost at closing.Authorizations in 2021 and 2022 from the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act and Inflation Reduction Act(dis
184、cussed in Section 4.1)include provisions that should help streamline the application process,along with associated fees,and also set aside$3.6 billion to cover the credit subsidy cost of loan guarantees(Brasher et al.2022).However,other requirements,such as the community benefits plan,have been adde
185、d,which may increase the time and cost burdens on project developers.Besides these obstacles during project selection,further challenges arise for selected projects.As in any program,the loan must be repaid on a defined schedule.Furthermore,loan agreements typically have covenants that may require p
186、roject developers to maintain a minimum cash balance(Brown 2012).For demonstration phase projects(TRLs 78),repayment requirements and covenants can potentially increase cash flow burdens,leading to liquidity issues.Having these debt service obligations in uncertain market conditions could be yet ano
187、ther burden facing innovative technologies that already face a host of other challenges.Related to this,projects supported by LPO loans and loan guarantees typically have a long payback period,which may be a poor match for the ever-changing renewable energy market(Brown 2012).Innovations funded by o
188、ther sources of private capital and federal programs could challenge the status quo of demonstration projects under LPO.Finally,with the large size requirement for selected projects and the LPOs limited capacity to fund programs,the total impact may be smaller than desirable.The lack of existing sch
189、olarship on the effectiveness of loan programs,as well as the scarcity of data on the net benefits of funded projects,makes it difficult to assess the magnitude of these challenges.In its annual portfolio status report,LPO publishes some data on avoided CO2 emissions and new jobs supported,but only
190、on an aggregate basis(LPO 2022).Further empirical analysis would be necessary to fully understand the trade-offs of LPOs programs.3.2.1.3.ARPA model of research fundingThe Advanced Research Projects Agency(ARPA)was first established by the US government in 1958 to improve the nations competitiveness
191、 in military and space-faring technologies.It later became the Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency(DARPA),shifting the focus of its projects and operations several times throughout its existence.The Advanced Research Projects AgencyEnergy(ARPA-E),instituted in 2009,is an organization modeled a
192、fter DARPA that seeks to fund innovations in the energy sector.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors18The ARPA model requires quantifiable goals and verifiable measures of progress.The intention of the program is to support high-risk,high-reward projects,with the
193、idea that returns to innovation are considerably skew-distributed,with a few big successes that justify the support of many different projects(Scherer and Harhoff 2000).Additionally,novel discoveries or inventions may be discarded by experts in the field as a result of bounded rationality(Boudreau e
194、t al.2016).This is addressed in the ARPA framework by accepting reviewer disagreement,as this implies uncertainty,which in turn may imply novelty(Azoulay et al.2019).In ARPA-E,projects are often selected for funding even when they fall below the peer-review cutoff line.More generally,the ARPA model
195、tackles this bias through individual discretion and selection of uncertain projects.In terms of process,ARPA-E follows the strategy of applying organizational flexibility,with a considerable degree of discretion given to individual directors of programs as well as researchers.Within this design,proj
196、ect managers are given individual responsibility,often constrained only by specific technical targets(Azoulay et al.2019).Moreover,research teams often comprise individuals from diverse backgrounds to stimulate synergies that would otherwise not form by themselves.The ARPA model also provides consid
197、erable flexibility for contracting,including the use of special types of agreements,such as with tailored terms regarding intellectual property.ARPA-E has been successful in developing nonincremental innovations,such as through its Grid-Scale Rampable Intermittent Dispatchable Storage(GRIDS)program.
198、The technical goal of$100 per kilowatt-hour was made a funding prerequisite,and the attainment of this target has become a fundamental step change,with the project benchmark becoming the new industry benchmark(Azoulay et al.2019).Transferring innovations to large-scale deployment in markets and faci
199、litating the wider diffusion of relevant new technologies have been significant issues for the ARPA model in practice.This is especially the case when the innovation is not subject to public procurement or some other demand guarantee.ARPA-E,for instance,seeks to address this issue with its tech-to-m
200、arket team but has been rather unsuccessful(Azoulay et al.2019).Thus,while the ARPA model has seen major success in delivering innovations with its use of R&D on the supply-push side,it has had less success in addressing the required demand-pull factors needed for widespread technology adoption.3.2.
201、2.Demand-pull policiesIn contrast to supply-push policies,which have traditionally been used by government in R&D,demand-pull policies,seeking to increase the demand for innovations,have been employed less frequently.We review the literature on the wide array of demand-pull policies in the following
202、 subsections.3.2.2.1.Inducement prizesPrizes are a demand-pull policy that were popular in the early days of innovation policy and have received increased interest in recent years.Inducement prizes are awards for achieving a specified ex ante goal,with the payout of the reward conditional on the win
203、ner achieving the goal.This ex ante specification distinguishes these prizes Resources for the Future19from awards that are paid out ex post for prior achievements.Inducement prizes may also encompass related forms of incentives that could be described as prizes,such as patent buyouts(Newell and Wil
204、son 2005;Davis and Davis 2004)or advance market commitments(AMCs)(Williams 2012).Prizes can include payments of cash or incentives in different forms,such as fast-track regulatory approval in the case of neglected diseases in the United States(Kremer and Williams 2010).3The literature suggests that
205、prizes are more effective than supply-push approaches at inducing nonincremental innovation when the desired goal is sufficiently well defined,but there is need for an inventive step to achieve the goal.Thus prizes seem to fit best for early TRL stages,notwithstanding that the highest-profile prize(
206、the X-Prize for private space missions)is very late-stage TRL.Good design of the prize contest is essential.In particular,prize design should feature technical specifications that are not too vague but not overly specific,with a goal that is relevant but also achievable and that can clearly lead to
207、ultimate commercialization.A particularly difficult aspect of design is the size of the prize needed to stimulate the necessary supply response and to be consistent with the social benefits that could result from the desired innovation.Good process is essential,too,such as certainty to participants
208、about the conditions for winning,including transparent governance and predictable rules.Publicity about the prize is important as well,as having a larger and more diverse set of participants can increase the likelihood of success.Another promising option is to have multiple prizes or prizes for diff
209、erent stages of the innovation development process.The latter can be considered an example of milestone payments,discussed in Section 3.2.2.4.This highlights a key disadvantage of prizes:they are paid out only when the innovation is complete,thus forcing innovators to raise capital in the hope that
210、they will win the prize.However,prizes lower the risk to lenders or grantees relative to situations without a clearly defined payout at the end.And entering a prize competition may be viewed by the financial markets,shareholders,and others as a nonmonetary benefit,such as from the publicity associat
211、ed with the prize and the learning and esprit de corps from mounting the effort to win(Murray et al.2012).At a 2020 NAS workshop on prizes,Hoyt Battey of DOE indicated that“prizes are well-suited when a desired outcome is cooperation and sharing of information among contest competitors,”noting that“
212、DOE has found that when they choose to use a prize,outcomes have been better than what they would have achieved through a traditional grant.”The workshop also promoted prizes to help build a community of practice.To garner a large pool of contestants,a suggestion was made to include the offer of som
213、e compensation to losers in the competition announcement(NAS 2020).3 This“priority review voucher”was first proposed by Ridley et al.(2006).Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors203.2.2.2.Public procurementGovernment procurement programs are another way of pulling
214、green products into the market.Because purchases by federal and state governments represent a significant part of overall material demand in the economy,public procurement can play a vital role in shaping and creating markets for green products.This role requires the government to set new or follow
215、existing standards for what a green product is and put in place a decision system for identifying winners among diverse bidders.While green procurement is not usually thought of as stimulating nonincremental innovations,it may induce innovation,as measured by patent activity(Krupnick 2020).In contra
216、st to traditional inducement prizes,however,the reward lies in the public demand for a certain product and may not be conditional on an innovative step underlying the procured product.In an early exploration of the influence of public procurement on innovation,Geroski(1990)finds that public procurem
217、ent may act as an innovation policy tool under certain conditions and in certain cases,such as national defense.However,it may be rendered ineffective if winners are wrongly picked and national champions declared,which hampers competition.It can also go wrong if ambition is too high and bidders cann
218、ot meet the requirements for clean projects.The current emphasis in the federal government is on green infrastructure projects,such as roads,bridges,and buildings,where green refers to the use of low-carbon-intensity cement and steel,for instance.This has external benefits to other governments and e
219、ven the private sector through standard setting(Krupnick 2020)and the creation of rules about how low costs and other traditional attributes of a desirable project are to be balanced against low carbon intensity,which can be expected to raise project costs(Hasanbeigi et al.2019).Ultimately,the idea,
220、beyond meeting immediate needs for roads,bridges,and buildings,is to stimulate clean product markets.However,one must watch for the effect of large procurements crowding out the development of private markets if the demand is too large(Krupnick 2020).3.2.2.3.Advance market commitmentsAdvance market
221、commitments(AMCs;sometimes called advance purchase commitments,or APCs)are a form of demand guarantee for yet-to-be-developed technologies.Sivaram et al.(2021)report that AMCs have shown notable success in the development of vaccines and are optimistic that these could also work for low-carbon techn
222、ologies for industry.AMCs in this space would guarantee the sale of a given amount of carbon reductions or low-carbon-intensity products at an agreed-upon price.Those committing to future purchases are not limited to governments.Indeed,major AMCs have been underwritten in several cases by private se
223、ctor companies seeking CO2 reduction credits toward their net-zero goals.AMCs are related to inducement prizes in that they promise a reward for successfully developing a desired technology.In contrast to prizes,however,they represent a Resources for the Future21binding legal contract with a specifi
224、c procurer of the technology,and the reward comes in the form of a demand guarantee,which can be from the government.This means that the reward payments are conditional on the actual use of the product to be developed and are thus subject to a“market test”(Kremer and Williams 2010).In a sense,advanc
225、e market commitments by the government can be thought of as a form of government procurement that includes a commitment to purchase a specific product before the technology is fully commercialized.First proposed by Kremer and Glennerster(2004),AMCs have mainly been applied in the pharmaceutical sect
226、or for the development of new drugs and vaccines in the context of neglected diseases.Before a product is developed or licensed,a number of sponsors underwrite a guaranteed price for a certain number of predetermined purchases(Kremer and Williams 2010).These purchases take place only when the techni
227、cal requirements of the innovation are met.Additionally,under the provisions of the AMC agreement,sponsors can agree to guarantee top-up payments on realized demand(e.g.,from a poor country purchasing the drug),while in turn,developers agree on a long-run price cap on the product or,alternatively,th
228、e licensing of their intellectual property to other manufacturers(Kremer and Williams 2010).AMCs showed spectacular success as a component of Operation Warp Speed to develop and scale up the production of vaccines for COVID-19.Kremer and Williams(2010)suggest that AMCs can extend prizes such as thos
229、e awarded by the X-Prize Foundation by conditioning the rewards on a market test.The types of market tests applied in AMCs could then inform more complex reward mechanisms,such as a medical prize fund.AMCs are not a substitute for broad market development,as winning companies are picked with varying
230、 degrees of a market test.Also,an AMC recipient can fail to deliver.The success of AMCs in the pharmaceutical sector may not carry over when applied to greenhouse gas abatement.Capital costs are significantly higher in steel and cement,whereas new pharmaceutical products have large market potential.
231、AMCs may thus be more costly overall in the materials sector than they are for vaccines.Optimal AMC design also depends on the technological distance of the desired innovation.Closer targets may be more feasible,but distant targets could be more efficient.AMCs must also be appropriately sized to hav
232、e an impact on decisionmaking.An AMC of a few million dollars is not likely to generate a significant change in behavior if the total capital investment in a new plant is$1 billion,as can be the case in the industrial sector.3.2.2.4.Milestone paymentsProviding milestone payments to innovators for th
233、e successful completion of innovative steps in the product development process can also support reaching certain innovation targets.Nemet et al.(2018)note that such payments can support learning from demonstration projects,as they base funding on created knowledge.Milestone payments can make R&D con
234、tracts more efficient by dealing with a Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors22number of problems in funding.these payments can be used to prevent asymmetric information between innovators and investors(private or public),as one party having more information than
235、another,regarding the value of the project or the probability of success,may lead to underinvestment(Bhattacharya 2015).The knowledge created may also decrease risk aversion on the part of investors,increasing investment.The precommitment aspects of milestone payments can mitigate holdup,where one p
236、arty may invest suboptimally because of concerns that it may not be able to fully appropriate the returns on its investment.Finally,by reducing the exposure to loss,milestone payments can reduce moral hazard,where one party is overly incentivized to take risks as it does not fully bear the downside
237、consequences.Milestone payments can be incorporated into different types of innovation incentives.For example,one could argue that the OCEDs Hydrogen Hubs Program is an example of a milestone-based approach,as it features four phases of funding,each based in part on performance in the previous phase
238、.Milestone payments are also used in private R&D partnership contracts and in projects of ARPA-type agencies(Azoulay et al.2019).Such payments have been successfully applied in aerospace technology and can complement other policies in early-stage innovation.3.2.2.5.Product and carbon intensity stand
239、ardsFollowing Swann(2000)and Blind(2016),standards can be seen as a type of infrastructure for innovation.They enable procurement programs that,for example,need carbon intensity benchmarks for deciding what is green steel and cement,and purchasers of green materials need to know whether they can tru
240、st these materials to perform adequately as an input to products(such as vehicles)and projects(such as building a bridge).Given that there may be trade-offs between various performance characteristics for steel and cement and the embodied carbon intensity,accepted standards for performance are essen
241、tial for green product markets to develop.Standard setting may have positive or negative impacts on innovation.Standards contribute to create additional opportunities for users,help reduce transaction costs,and facilitate trade of complex products,and they can form the basis of subsequent innovation
242、s.They naturally limit the options for new technologies to be realized,however.This can help in the development of critical mass in those technologies,which is a traditional concern of demand-pull policy in innovation.Moreover,by increasing credibility in the technologies,standards can attract furth
243、er investments and spur the development of complementary technologies.For established technologies,standards can help bring about economies of scale.The scaling up of technologies is an important component of overcoming the valley of death.Also,as Blind(2016)argues,standards may enable firms to gene
244、rate the necessary profits to reappropriate some of their investments in innovation.In this regard,standards act as an effective leveraging and diffusion mechanism for patent rights.Finally,standardization reduces the risk of new products,which increases users trust in innovative technologies.Resour
245、ces for the Future23Standards also have some potential challenges and downsides.The main challenge is to set standards for the appropriate product classes.It would make no sense to set the same intensity standard for all steel products,for instance,since their carbon footprints are so heterogeneous.
246、The Buy Clean California Act,for example,sets intensity standards for four steel products,from 0.9 t CO2e per metric ton for concrete reinforcing steel to 1.7 t CO2e for structural steel.4 Some other downsides are mentioned by Blind(2016)and Swann(2000),mainly pertaining to the potential adverse eff
247、ects on market concentration.Market concentration and monopolistic market structures tend to stifle innovation by reducing the pressure to innovate.Specifically,standards may be dominated by single companies(e.g.,if they hold the patents necessary for their implementation),leading to a concentrated
248、market.Standards set at a high level of ambition might lead to prohibitively high implementation costs,which can deter new entrants and thereby reduce competition.Even without intellectual property restrictions,standards have the potential to lock in outdated technologies(Blind 2016).Especially radi
249、cal innovations are sometimes delayed significantly by the presence of standards.When placed appropriately,standards can help avoid lock-in on old technologies by ensuring compatibility between old and new technologies.However,standards run the risk of selecting technologies prematurely.Blind(2016)n
250、otes that these factors can mostly be mitigated by open and transparent standardization processes.More frequent updating of standards can help mitigate these lock-in problems as well.The design of the procurement program can also mitigate the problems with standards.One idea,suggested by Krupnick(20
251、20),is to create multiple standards of ever more“greenness”and provide project scoring systems that award more points for meeting tighter standards in the bidding process.Blind(2016)notes that implementing a new standard has a direct innovation effect on companies as potential suppliers.This then ma
252、y have positive spillover effects into the private sector.Moreover,standards reduce the risks related to costs,health,the environment,and safety for the public procurer and consequently create leeway for the procurement of products and services with innovative characteristics.However,the implementat
253、ion of technical standards in tenders requires a deep understanding of the technological environment and the market landscape in which the procurer is operating.Ghosh(2005)points out that the combination of patents,standards,and public procurement can lead to a triple dividend for dominant market pa
254、rticipants,creating considerable market inefficiencies.3.2.2.6.Carbon contracts for differenceA contract for difference(CfD)is a form of financial derivative that exchanges a fixed return for a floating return,in a manner similar to a commodity swap.In electricity markets,for example,a CfD would pay
255、 the difference between the wholesale 4 Buy Clean California Act of 2017,Public Contract Code 35003505,https:/www.dgs.ca.gov/PD/Resources/Page-Content/Procurement-Division-Resources-List-Folder/Buy-Clean-California-ActDemand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors24price o
256、f electricity and a predetermined strike price.The price could be set either administratively or through an auction.This instrument has been used by governments to subsidize energy investment by removing price risk.5 A number of variations on this instrument have arisen in recent years.In one varian
257、t discussed by Bollerhey et al.(2022),an entity is created that procures a clean commodity such as hydrogen via long-term contracts.The entity then sells the commodity to off-takers on a short-term basis through a competitive bidding process.The government will cover any losses due to price differen
258、ces in the contracts.In this way,the entity provides both price and duration certainty to the producers,reducing their risk.The competitive nature of the procurement and sales should,to some extent,reduce the risk to the government to cover the entitys losses and bridge the gap in prices between the
259、 supply and demand sides over time.Another variation on the CfD gaining increased attention is the carbon contract for difference(CCfD).Unlike the example of Bollerhey et al.(2022),this policys purpose is to counter the innovation-depressing effects of the uncertainty and volatility of an allowance
260、price in a cap-and-trade system(or other carbon price policy)rather than the price of a physical commodity.With CCfDs,if the carbon price is below a government-set strike price,the government will pay the difference between the strike price and the actual price of carbon multiplied by the abatement
261、achieved by the contractee.In some versions of a CCfD,the contractee must pay the government if the carbon price rises above the strike price.By derisking the emissions price,CCfDs can boost investor confidence and help commercialize new low-carbon technologies.This instrument may not make much sens
262、e in the United States because of a lack of general carbon pricing outside of California and the Northeast.With appropriate design,CCfDs can be highly cost-effective in reducing risk.Proper design must set the right strike price and select eligible projects through a tender process.3.2.2.7.Additiona
263、l demand-pull featuresMany demand-pull tools involve a price being set:the prize amount,the strike price of a CfD or CCfD,and the price paid for CO2 reductions in an AMC,for example.Other tools,such as green procurement,are inherently competitions that set pricesin this case,prices on projects(e.g.,
264、building a road)rather than prices of products(e.g.,steel)or processes.However,price setting can be tricky when market forces are not present.In such cases,one option is to use an auction among competitors.When sellers compete to offer the most attractive price for their supply decision,this is call
265、ed a reverse auction and would apply to some of the demand-pull policies.For instance,competitors for a prize could include in their application the prize they need to supply the performance terms.Similarly,an AMC could be structured to get the applicants to state the price they 5 The use of CfDs by
266、 state governments to subsidize generation was ruled to be in viola-tion of the Federal Power Act in Hughes v.Talen.Resources for the Future25need to supply the requisite CO2 reductions.In these cases,the demander(or buyer),whether government or private sector entity,could decide to take the lowest
267、bid or consider other factors in deciding which bid or bids to accept.The buyer,if terms allow,might also use these revealed prices to set a prize amount or strike price with more certainty than without a price discovery process.3.2.3.Regulations and Tax CreditsSupply-push and demand-pull policies a
268、re those focused directly on innovation and often on specific technologies or systems in need of progress.These approaches are sometimes embedded in a complex web of alternative activities driving innovation directly or indirectly.The first of these is regulation.We do not consider the advantages an
269、d disadvantages of all types of regulations here,but in general,for efficiency,taxes,tradable permits,and to a lesser degree tradable performance standards are preferred because they let the regulated entity decide the most cost-effective approach to reduce emissions.While these incentives can lead
270、to innovation,they may instead drive the deployment of extant emissions reduction technologies.And to the extent that standards must be set and met,they discourage innovation efforts greener than the standard.A form of environmental regulation is mandates,such as renewable portfolio standards,which
271、we use here to illustrate the advantages and disadvantages of this form of regulation to innovation.These standards mandate that electric utilities demonstrate that a certain percentage of their generation is from renewable sources,such as wind and solar power.These standards exist in many states bu
272、t not at the national level.Unquestionably,these standards(along with supply-push funding from DOE)have pushed innovation in renewable energy technology to bring costs down to a remarkable degreeboth from economies of scale in their production and from stimulating technological innovation.However,th
273、ey encourage utilities to just meet the standard but not go beyond it.They also are not particularly applicable to lower-TRL technologies unless the standard is designed with long lead times in required compliance.The flip side of regulations is subsidies,which get actors to do something by making i
274、t worth their while rather than by requiring compliance.The spate of tax credits in the Inflation Reduction Act(for clean hydrogen and carbon capture,for instance)fall into this category.Economists are generally suspicious of subsidies because they can encourage bad behavior to be eligible for the s
275、ubsidies and they build strong constituencies for keeping them going.They are often open-ended(as the new credits are)and lack a strong accountability system(except IRS audits),and they reduce government revenue or raise government expenses.Maybe worst of all,when particular technologies are targete
276、d,they pick winners rather than let the market decide,as some other forms of regulation do.That is,subsidy programs tend to be sector,fuel,or technology specific when a better approach is to regulate through performance standards or taxes and tradable permits that directly target emissions and let t
277、he market decide which solutions make economic sense.Demand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors263.2.4.Summary of ToolsIn our review of tools to deliver greenhouse gas mitigation innovations,we have examined a variety of attributes for judging the applicability of a to
278、ol:the scale and scope desired,the readiness level of the technologies involved,the number of competitors,the size of the budget,and many others.It would be desirable to have a checklist whereby tools could be chosen based on their performance with respect to the attributes of the particular case in
279、 need of a tool,but alas,with so many attributes and relatively few tools,such a tidy approach is not feasible in general.Nonetheless,our analysis has highlighted some relations.For example,prizes seem to work best with earlier-stage technologies and a number of competitors.With an advance market co
280、mmitment,it is clear that the size must be sufficient to have a material impact on the economics of the producers.In Section 5,where we consider applications specific to the steel and cement sectors,we match tools to specific situations where innovation is needed.4.Developments in Government Funding
281、 for InnovationIn this section,we discuss some developments in both supply-push and demand-pull government policies directed at the industrial sector,as well as tax credits that apply to any sector.A number of these demand-pull policies are already employed in the energy sector.Three major pieces of
282、 legislation passed in 202122 and an important executive order on green procurement gave these efforts a huge boost.In addition to reviewing the impacts of the three laws,this section provides an overview of ongoing federal government activity in the use of prizes and in green procurement.4.1.Releva
283、nt Legislation4.1.1.Infrastructure Investment and Jobs ActIn late 2021,the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act(IIJA),also known as the Bipartisan Infrastructure Law,appropriated$1 trillion of public investment to upgrade roads,bridges,power grids,and other infrastructure all over the country duri
284、ng 202226.Of most relevance here,the package allocates$31 billion for RD&D in green technologies,mostly to be administered as competitive grants by DOE.The funds cover RD&D in clean hydrogen and carbon capture,advanced batteries,advanced nuclear,and direct air capture technologies.A key piece of the
285、 legislation focuses on CCUS technologies.The IIJA expands several DOE programs,with$310 million targeted to the Carbon Utilization Program to include the development of standards and certifications to support commercialization of carbon oxide products.Along with the standardization of carbon oxide
286、products,this program awards grants to local authorities to use or procure products derived from the capture of carbon oxides.By focusing on the commercialization of carbon capture outputs,this Resources for the Future27piece of the legislation can be understood as a demand-pull instrument.The bill
287、also expands the Carbon Capture Technology Program to include pipeline infrastructure,with an additional$100 million over the next five years.This is to be administered by the National Energy Technology Laboratory(NETL),which awards funding to selected RD&D projects.These funds are not for RD&D itse
288、lf but would facilitate market growth.Other programs implemented or expanded by the IIJA include the Advanced Energy Manufacturing and Recycling Grant Program($750 million),the Carbon Dioxide Transportation Finance and Innovation Program($2.1 billion),and the Large-Scale Carbon Storage Commercializa
289、tion Program($2.5 billion).The IIJA also adds funding to the existing Carbon Capture Large-Scale Pilot Programs($937 million)and Carbon Capture Demonstration Projects Program($2.5 billion).Similarly,the Carbon Removal Program provides$3.5 billion for the development and demonstration of four regiona
290、l direct air capture(DAC)hubs.The IIJA legislation also appropriates new funding for DAC Technology Prize Competitions(DOE,n.d.).Funding for green hydrogen is another key part of the IIJA,with$9.5 billion for different programs in the sector.The bill expands the scope of DOEs Hydrogen Research and D
291、evelopment Program,focusing on the demonstration and commercialization of clean hydrogen production,processing,delivery,and end-use application technologies.Additionally,while mandating the development of a national strategy and roadmap to facilitate a clean hydrogen economy,the bill establishes thr
292、ee new RD&D programs:the Regional Clean Hydrogen Hubs Program($8 billion),the Clean Hydrogen Manufacturing and Recycling Program($500 million),and a demonstration,commercialization,and deployment program to decrease cost of clean hydrogen production from electrolyzers($1 billion).Eligible entities w
293、ill receive grants on a competitive basis from DOE.The IIJA allocates$10M to demonstration projects for energy storage of intermittent renewable electricity.While not directly relevant to industrial decarbonization,energy storage is important for complementing plans to make the grid as low-carbon as
294、 possible and therefore lower the carbon footprint of industries choosing to substitute electricity for fossil fuels in their processes or to meet heating needs.The bill provides funding to two other energy storage programs,the Energy Storage Demonstration Projects and Pilot Grant Program and the Lo
295、ng-Duration Demonstration Initiative and Joint Program,amounting to$355 million and$150 million,respectively.The Advanced Reactor Demonstration Program receives$3 billion for the period 202226.Again,while not directly linked to industrial decarbonization,this program could help make the grid cleaner
296、.Similarly,while battery development is not directly tied to industrial decarbonization,the IIJA supports the DOEs ongoing Lithium-Ion Battery Recycling Prize with an additional$10 million to carry out Phase III.These programs are open to both private and public entities.The IIJA also created the Of
297、fice of Clean Energy Demonstrations(OCED),discussed in Section 2.2,to be in charge of the management of demonstration projects.OCED conducts project management and oversight of all the demonstration projects we have mentioned and more,representing$22 billion of investment in demonstration projects.D
298、emand-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors28In early 2023,OCED issued a request for information(RFI)on the use of demand-side mechanisms to support clean energy.This RFI focuses on many mechanisms discussed in this paper,including direct procurement,AMCs,and price floor
299、s(which it takes to include CfDs).4.1.2.Inflation Reduction ActPassed in the fall of 2022,the Inflation Reduction Act(IRA)created or modified many relevant programs for industrial decarbonization.Most important are two tax credit programs,45Q and 45V,for promoting CCUS and clean hydrogen,respectivel
300、y.The first program provides$85 per metric ton for captured and sequestered carbon oxides.This is a substantial increase from the maximum of$50 per metric ton available under previous iterations of this tax credit.The 45Q tax credit increases to$180 per metric ton for carbon dioxide sequestered from
301、 direct air capture.The 45V tax credit provides up to$3/kg H2 for hydrogen production with a life-cycle carbon intensity below 0.45 kg CO2e/kg H2,with lower amounts for more carbon-intensive production,falling to zero for life-cycle emissions above 4.0 kg CO2e/kg H2.These tax credits are explained i
302、n more detail in an RFF report by Krupnick and Bergman(2022).The IRA makes a substantial investment in green procurement,discussed in Section 4.2.Numerous other tax credits in the bill are aimed at reducing emissions from electricity production;increasing the availability of components of clean ener
303、gy technologies,including critical minerals;reducing the cost of electrification of demand in the residential,commercial,and transportation sectors;increasing the adoption of clean vehicles;and deploying clean fuels.With respect to the industrial sector,the IRA includes$5.812 billion for OCED for th
304、e Advanced Industrial Facilities Deployment Program and a revival of the 48C tax credit,with$10 billion for clean manufacturing.The IRA appropriates$11.7 billion to the LPO to support approximately$100 billion in new loans,as well as$5 billion for the new Energy Infrastructure Reinvestment Program i
305、n the LPO,with authority to provide loans up to$250 billion.This legislation also includes a large number of provisions not directly related to the industrial sector,such as funds for a Greenhouse Gas Reduction Fund(related to the green bank concept)and a fee on methane emissions.4.1.3.CHIPS and Sci
306、ence ActDomestic manufacturing of microchips and semiconductors is at the core of the CHIPS and Science Act passed during the summer of 2022,with an investment of$50 billion in the development of an American supply chain.In addition to the semiconductor funding in the bill,it appropriates$67 billion
307、 for DOE,with the majority going to the Office of Science,which will fund early TRL R&D of clean energy and advanced computing technologies(DOE 2022e).This legislation also establishes a new nongovernmental foundation,the Foundation for Energy Security and Innovation(FESI),which will collaborate wit
308、h DOE to reach goals such as advancing R&D to tackle climate change and protecting energy independence.FESI will be in charge of encouraging public-private partnerships between government,Resources for the Future29industry incumbents,start-ups,and other funding entities to foster collaboration in in
309、novation ecosystems and bridge the valley of death(Duggan and Hart 2022).4.2.Green Procurement InitiativesBeginning in 2021,a number of administrative and legislative actions have combined to set up the federal government and,through the federal Highway Trust Fund(a$49 billion/year road and bridge f
310、unding support program),state governments to procure roads,bridges,and new building construction that use steel,cement,and other materials with a lower carbon footprint.In the FY2023 Omnibus Appropriations Bill,DOE was directed to start a program to purchase carbon dioxide from direct air capture.DO
311、E has not yet announced how it will implement this directive,so we focus here on federal procurement of green construction materials.In December 2021,the Biden administration issued Executive Order 14057 on Catalyzing Clean Energy Industries and Jobs through Federal Sustainability.This includes a Bu
312、y Clean Task Force to make recommendations on how to promote the use of low-carbon steel,cement,and other construction materials in federally funded projects.The General Services Administration(GSA)has already issued a set of new rules,which set limits on the embodied carbon of concrete procured for
313、 its construction projects.The IRA appropriates over$2 billion to the Federal Building Fund for efforts that support the use of low-carbon materials in buildings and construction under GSAs control.The legislation also appropriates$2 billion to the Federal Highway Administration to incentivize the u
314、se of low-carbon materials in construction projects.It appropriates$100 million to EPA to develop a labeling system for construction materials that have a substantially lower carbon footprint than the industry average to be used in these construction projects.These provisions amount to$4.5 billion t
315、o help boost the Federal Buy Clean Initiative.Another$3 billion is slated to go toward the purchase of electric vehicles and associated infrastructure(e.g.,charging stations)by the US Postal Service.Further,the IRA provides$250 million for EPA to develop environmental product declarations for whatev
316、er materials sectors and products the agency deems appropriate.Environmental Product Declarations(EPDs)are third-party verified documents specifying the emissions and other types of waste products and environmental results.An EPD includes information on the manufacturer,product characteristics,life-
317、cycle assessment methodology used,material feedstock and chemical content,global warming potential,waste streams,and potential environmental certifications.However,an EPD contains no information related to compliance with any environmental standards.The federal government will likely develop standar
318、ds for use in EPDs to comply with the Buy Clean Initiative.EPDs can be used to compare environmental performance between similar products made by different manufacturers or using different technologies.Green building certifications and rating systems,such as LEED,often require EPDs during the Demand
319、-Pull Tools for Innovation in the Cement and Iron and Steel Sectors30evaluation process.EPDs are already widely used in the cement and concrete sector.The New Buildings Institute collected data from more than 36,000 US-based ready-mix concrete EPDs(NBI 2022).This large number can be explained by the
320、 fact that EPDs in the cement and concrete sector are product-based and hundreds of mixes are possible with various levels of each ingredient,especially to make concrete.By comparison,steel is a highly standardized product,so there are fewer product-level EPDs.In the same study,only 100 internationa
321、l EPDs for steel were collected,with some products widely underrepresented.The Federal Buy Clean Initiative prioritizes the use of low-carbon construction materials for federally funded projects and requires EPDs to measure the embodied carbon of the procured materials.GSA has set limits for each cl
322、ass of concrete at 20 percent lower than the industry limit set at the 75th percentile of all embodied carbon values by NBI(2022).The Buy Clean California Act also defines embodied carbon limits for structural steel using the industry average for each type of steel product.4.3.PrizesDOE first receiv
323、ed the authority to issue prizes under the Energy Policy Act of 2005.We have found reference to an efficient-lighting prize competition as far back as 2008(Brennan et al.2012).Prizes were given a big boost throughout the federal government in 2011 when the America COMPETES Reauthorization Act became
324、 law,authorizing a broader use of prize competitions than under existing authorities.This authority was then modified under the American Innovation and Competitiveness Act of 2017.Every other year,under the COMPETES Reauthorization Act,the Office of Science and Technology Policy in the Executive Off
325、ice of the President issues a report on the use of prizes throughout the federal government.6A US government website lists all federal prize competitions and serves as an information hub for federal prize managers and others;DOE prizes are listed on this site,but DOE also has its own prize websites.
326、7 As of February 2023,nine open prize competitions were listed.Competitions cover such things as innovation in energy storage,wind energy,developing high conductivity cables,digitizing electric utilities,and advanced building lighting systems.Together,over$170 million in prize money is offered.An ad
327、ditional 16 prizes are in progress and 20 competitions are closed.The numbers of competitions and funds available pale in comparison to policies using supply-push tools.However,most challenges are tightly focused and for low-TRL technologies,which do not necessarily require expensive efforts.6 For t
328、he most recent report as of this writing,see https:/www.whitehouse.gov/ostp/news-updates/2022/05/04/white-house-office-of-science-technology-policy-releas-esfiscal-year-2019-20-federal-prize-and-citizen-science-authority-report/.7 The federal prize website is https:/www.challenge.gov.One of DOEs pri
329、ze websites is https:/americanmadechallenges.org,run by the National Renewable Energy Laboratory.Resources for the Future31In considering prize processes and designs,DOEs EERE issued a prize guidance document that details all the necessary design steps(EERE 2019).The guidelines note that prizes are
330、especially suited to,among other things,increasing the number and diversity of innovators involved,encouraging risk-taking while having transparent and predictable rules,and reaching innovation goals without picking winners.These characteristics are also highlighted in the academic literature for pr
331、izes.The prize goals,reward size,winning criteria,and other rules are defined at the very beginning of the EERE prize process.They are included in a comprehensive prize rule document,which serves as a reference for the participants.In addition,to address potential uncertainties about winning conditi
332、ons,a mandatory webinar and public Q&A platform must be put in place after publication of the rules.Prize managers are encouraged to consult different experts and other EERE staff who have successfully developed prize competitions to inform their decisionmaking.Wider consultations,through RFIs and w
333、orkshops,should be held when selecting prize topics.This helps define the goals and other characteristics of the competition.EERE guidance promotes the use of different prize designs to achieve different missions and goals.The guidelines establish that precise technical goals and the size of the reward should be set according to the issues the prize program is looking to address.Prizes promoted by